In a market who is the marginal buyer




















Marginal producer is the producer who would be eliminated from competition by a drop in the market price or a rise in his production costs because his production costs are the nearest at the margin to the current market price.

How do you calculate producer surplus? Where is consumer surplus on a graph? Consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve see the graph below that represents the difference between what a consumer is willing and able to pay for a product, and what the consumer actually ends up paying. Can producer surplus be negative? Consumer surplus is their willingness to pay minus the price they pay, and producer surplus is the price they receive minus their willingness to receive.

So if you are assuming that consumers are forced to buy at a price of , yes the consumer surplus is negative. How price affects consumer surplus? Assuming that there is no shift in demand, an increase in price will therefore lead to a reduction in consumer surplus, while a decrease in price will lead to an increase in consumer surplus.

This means that consumers will be able to purchase the product at a lower price than what would normally be available to them. How are buyers willingness to pay consumer surplus and the demand curve related?

The price a buyer is willing to pay, consumer surplus, and the demand curve are all closely related. Consumer surplus is the area below the demand curve and above the price, which equals the price that each buyer is willing to pay minus the price actually paid.

What is consumer surplus in equilibrium? People vary greatly in their desire for a particular product, which is measured by their willingness to pay , the maximum amount that a buyer will pay for a good.

Some people will not be willing to pay the market price , so they will do without the product. Others are willing to pay much more than the market price, but since the market price is set by competition and the market demand for the product, with the result that the same price will be charged to everyone, those people willing to pay more for the good will be able to get it for the market price.

The amount that a consumer is willing to pay minus the amount actually paid results in a consumer surplus for the consumer. Thus, marginal buyers do not enjoy a consumer surplus. Paddles all around the room compete furiously as the auction starts; but as the bid price rises higher and higher, fewer and fewer paddles participate in the bidding.

Pretty soon, it's down to just two bidders dueling back and forth with one another. The marginal buyer has been found. No one is willing to outbid his price. For the record, this is exactly what happened back in when Picasso's Nude, Green Leaves and Bust came up for sale. This example contains several important elements for price-setting.

First: the marginal buyer's last bid is what ends up setting the final price. Now imagine what would have happened if our marginal buyer above hadn't shown up the auction. Maybe he got stuck in traffic, or decided he'd rather own a tropical island instead of a wall hanging. How much would the painting have sold for then?

It would have sold at a price lower than the losing bidder's last offer. Without our hero in the room, the losing bidder would have become the new marginal buyer. And without the threat from a competitor with deeper pockets, it's quite likely our new marginal buyer would have been able to secure the painting at a substantially lower price. The takeaway from the above is that prices are set by two things: the upper limit that the marginal buyer is willing to pay, and how intensely the competition from other buyers pushes him towards that limit.

And we're now seeing some concerning signs that the marginal buyers, as well as their competitors, are beginning to go on strike across those asset classes. Let's look at the stock market. For the past 5 years, stock prices have been powering higher. Good, right?



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000